Economic
Growth and Structural Changes in Employment and Investments
in China, 1985-94
Research
Fellow and Reader in Economics,
Development Economics Research
Group,
Department of Economics,
University
of Portsmouth, UK Aying Liu and Shuffle Yao
I.Introduction
One
of the most striking features in China´s economic reform is an increasitig
polarisation between the prosperous eastern coastal provinces and the still
backward western parts of the country. Regional income inequality has been
widening considerably under economic reforms (Yao, I 997a). This has been
accompanied by dramatic changes in employment and investment structures
at both the national and regional levels.
First,
there is an increasing surplus of labour released from agriculture due
to increased labour productivity and shortage of land. Second, an increasing
number of workers and staff employed by state-owned enterprises (SOEs)
have become um- or underemployed due to market liberalization and fierce
competition from the private sectors. Third, and most impressively, employment
and investments have been shifted or diversified away from agriculture
to manufacturing and services, and from heavy and defence-based industries
to light industries (Zhao, 1996).
Structural changes
in employment and investments have followed a clear regional pattern. The
most prosperous provinces and metropolitan cities, especially Shanghai,
Beijing, Tianjin, Guangdong and Jiangsu have succeeded in making their
economies similar to those of the newly industrialized countries (NICs)
in southeast Asia, with per capita gross domestic product (GDP) similar
to that of a middle income country (S 1000-2000), a large and increasing
proportion of the service sectors and a decreasing proportion of agriculture
and manufacturing in the regional economies. On the other hand, the western
provinces still resemble the low income developing economies, with per
capita GDP less than $400 and a predominant role of agriculture in the
local economies. The rest of the country has made a significant progress
in the process of industrialization with rapid growth in both manufacturing
and services, but economic development has been constrained by the old
industrial structure and planning system which need to be fundamentally
re-organized as economic reforms reach the stronghold of SOEs.
The
diversity and complexity of the Chinese economy in its industrialization
drive have important theoretical and empirical implications in economic
development. From a theoretical point of view, one should not look at a
large economy like China´s as a simple and homogenous nation. A new
approach of research has to be adopted in order to fully understand the
whole process of industrialization and economic development. This new approach
is to examine the country via a multi-tier (different groups of regions)
and multi-stage (different stages of industrialization) development perspective.
First, one should not overlook the importance of some dynamic and powerful
regions in a large country that is regarded as a poor economy as a whole
from outside. Deng's development philosophy to set up four special economic
zones (SEA) and to open up fourteen coastal cities in the early 1980s was
precisely aiming at creating a few fresh growing centres in a country largely
dogged by socialist doctrines and by a mono-structure of state ownership.
Second, one needs to study whether rapid industrialization in these growing
centres can eventually lead the rest of the country to change and develop
in a similar way.
Several studies on
multi-tier and multi-stage development in China can be found in the literature
although theoretically such a strategy has not been formalized. Yao (1997a)
studies the negative aspects of such a development strategy through analysing
regional income inequality in rural China; Zhao (1996) focuses on a time-series
comparison of regional disparities between the development policies of
Mao and Deng. There are also other studies (Knight and Song, 1993; Griffin
and Zhao, 1993; Hussain et al., 1994), but it appears that all of them
examine disparity in terms of income distribution and none of them has
studied the causes of regional inequality. This is the primary objective
of this study. We examine the structural changes in employment and investments
between industries at both the national and provincial levels by use of
a shift-share method. It explains not only the structural change of the
whole country by industry but also how comparable changes at provincial
level have been driven by a national trend in general and a national trend
by industry in particular. The residual change by industry for a particular
province after excluding the national trend and national industrial trend
will reflect the extent to which the province under concern outperforms
or is left behind by other regions. By studying the structural changes
for all the regions, we are able to identify the growing centres and to
see whether the rest of the country are catching up.
In
brief, China experienced substantial structural changes in the national
economy. The relative importance of agriculture declined, whilst the non-agricultural
sectors, especially the service industries sustained continuous and rapid
growth. At the provincial level, three distinctive development models emerged;
the growing-centre model, the catching-up model, and the backward model.
The growing-centre model was exemplified by Guangdong (including Beijing,
Shanghai, Jiangsu and other rich and fast growing regions). This model
was characterized by the followingfeatures: high and rapidly
growing per capita GDP which was above 51,000 in 1996, a small and declining
agriculture's share and a large and growing services sector's share in
the regional economy. massive foreign direct investments and active participation
in international trade. On the other extreme, the backward model was exemplified
by Gansu (Including most western parts of the country). This model was
characterized by low per capita GDP (less than $400 in 1996), poor infrastructure,
poor technologies and lack of skilled labour, lack of investments, and
low participation in international trade. In between the growing centre
and the western provinces was the catching-up model (including most provinces
in central, northeaster and northern China) where the regional
economies were dominated by SOEs and heavy industries but significant changes
hadtaken place in a drive to diversify their economies and
to break away from the former socialist doctrines and rigidity of central
planning.
The
rest of this paper is organised as follows. Section 11 gives a brief introduction
of the shift-share method and the data used in the study. Section 111 presents
the results of shift-share analyses on GDP growth, employment and investment
changes for all provinces by three aggregate industrial sectors. The results
lead to some important conclusions and policy implications in Section IV.
II.Shift-Share
Analysis
Shift-share
is a standardised and useful analytical tool for spatial analysis. since
its introduction in 1960, it has been widely used for analyses of regional
employment, structural change affecting different industries, industrial
location, migration and economic growth. The method (together with its
merits and limitations) is extensively discussed in Stillwell (1970), Fothergill
and Gudgin (1979), Stevens and Moore (1980), Casler (1989), Armstrong and
Taylor (1993), and Hoppes (1994). Some examples of its use in examing employment
change, growth and productivity are found in Moore and Rhodes (1973); Randall
(1973); Healey and Clark (1984); and Ishikawa (1992) among others. A recent
discussion and application of the method can be found in liu et al
(1996).
Over
the years, the basic technique has been extended and refined. A number
of alternative models have appeared in the literature, such as the Esteban-Marquilas
(1972) and Arcelus (1984). Some of those models have enriched or improved
the original method by linking shift-share with other techniques such as
statistics (Berzeg, 1978; Kurre and Weller, 1989), information theory (Theil
and Gosh, 1980), and stochastic regression functions (Arcelus, 1984; Knudson
and Barff 1991; Selting and Loveridge, 1994). The classic formulation,
however, remains the most dominant model in empirical work.
This study adopts
the most basic version of the model discussed in buns (1960) and Armstrong
and Taylor (1993). LetDEijdenote the change of employment
(or investments) for the ith industry in region j from the
base period to the end period. By definition, it is the product of total
employment of the ith sector in region j in the base period, denoted by
Eij0, multiplied by the growth rate of employment of
the ith sector in region j over the whole period, denoted by Rij.
The relationship is expressed in equation (1).
DEij=
Eij0Rij(1)
Further,
let Rk and Rik denote the employment
growth rates for the country and for the ith sector of the country respectively.
Equation (1) can then be decomposed into three components as expressed
in equation (2).
DEij=
Eij0Rk + Eij0(Rik - Rk)
+ Eij0(Rij - Rik)(2)
The
first term on the right hand side of (2) is usually called the national
coniponent of growth. It shows ceteris paribus, the
effect on the sector of the local economy, if sector 1 in location j exactly
matched the national trend ( Rk ).
The
second term in equation (2) is the structural component. It
calculates the change in the ith sector that can be attributed to the region's
industry mix. If the region has a 'favourable' mix, comprising more fast
growing industries, it will , ceteris paribus, experience
faster employment growth than the rest of the country.
However,
having a favourable industrial structure in the base period is neither
a necessary, nor a sufficient condition for faster growth. Hence the third
term in equation (2) is the differential (or residual) component.
It
is that part of regional change not ‘xplained’by the national and structural
components. It is a catch-all for measuring the extent to which an industry
in the region grew faster (shown by a positive value) or slower (shown
by a negative value) than would have occurred had the local industry experienced
the national growth rate. Therefore, the sign and size of the structural
and differential components have very important economic implications in
terms of structural adjustment and improvement in local competitiveness.
Following Randall
(1973), equation (2) can be rearranged as equation (3).
DEij-
E ij0Rk = Eij0(Rik - Rk)
+ Eij0(Rij -Rik)(3)
The
left hand side is called the net relative change (NRC), meaning the difference
between the actual change and the national component. It shows whether
growth of the ith sector in region j is faster or slower than the national
average growth irrespective of industrial structure. NRC can
therefore be regarded as an index of relative performance, which the right
hand side seeks to explain.
The
data used in this study are drawn from China's Statistical Yearbook (SSB,
1985-95). Three sets of regional and sectoral data are employed in both
absolute and growth rate terms: (1) gross domestic product (GDP), (2) employment,
and (3) investments in basic construction.1While
GDP is used as an indicator of economic development, employment and investments
are used for analysing some of the reasons behind the disparities in economic
growth.
Ill
Results of spatial disparity analysis
III.AAn
overall view of changes
Over the data period
1985-94, the Chinese economy grew rapidly. Real GDP more than doubled (about
8.3 per cent per year). Investments on basic construction rose by 134.3,
and employment by 23.3 per cent (Table I)- Such growth was, however, by
no means even across sectors and regions.
Table
1 Growth of GDP, employment and investments by sectors, 1985-94(%)
|
Total
|
Agriculture
|
Agriculture
|
Industry
|
Industry
|
Services
|
Services
|
|
Actual
|
Actual
|
NRC
|
Actual
|
NRC
|
Actual
|
NRC
|
GDP
|
107,1
|
41,6
|
-55,5
|
119,2
|
12,1
|
160,4
|
53,3
|
Employment
|
23,3
|
7,1
|
-16,2
|
34,0
|
10,8
|
70,8
|
47,6
|
investment
|
134,3
|
-45,4
|
-179,7
|
139,4
|
-5,1
|
142,5
|
8,1
|
Notes:
Growth rates are measured
in 1994 constant prices. NRC = sectoral actual growth rate minus national
growth rate. Total GDPs in 1985 are national incomes (NI)
in that year multiplied by the average GDP/NI ratios of 1988, 1989 and
1990 for each province. Agricultural and indu strial GDPs
in 1985 are estimated by multiplying the respective sectoral NIs with sectoral
GDP/N 1 ratios in 1991 for each province. Price indices are
RPIs for each province. Industry includes extraction, utilities, manufacturing
and construction -- this definition applies in all the other
tables hereafter. Hence, agriculture, industry and services in this paper
correspond respectively to the first, second and third industries defined
by the SSB of China.
Sources:
SSB
(1985-95), various issues.
There
was a dramatic shift between three aggregated sectors. Real investments
in agriculture declined by 45.4 per cent. Employment rose by only 7.1 per
cent. On the other hand, the services sector experienced the most rapid
growth. GDP increased by 160.4 per cent, investments 142.5 per cent and
employment 70.8 per cent. In relative terms (NRC), both industry and services
experienced higher than national average growth in GDP, investments and
employment. In agriculture, NRC was
1Investments
in basic construction include investments that can create new capital assets
for production but excludes investments that are used for renovations,
or for replacement of old capital assets. In the official statistics, we
can only obtain data on basic construction investments of the state-owned
sectors by province. However, such data are sufficient to reflect the extent
of regional disparities in investments.
|
negative
in all the three indicators.
Given
the national and structural influence on economic growth, however, the
actual changes varied from one region to another. The difference between
the actual and relative changes can be apportioned to the regional industry-mix
component and the differential component , and it is to this that we now
turn at a more spatially disaggregated level.
III.BShift-share
analysis of GDP growth by province
The
results of shift-share analysis on GDP growth by province and by sector
are presented in Table 2. In terms of total GDP, all provinces that outperformed
the national average were located along the eastern coasts except Hebei,
Henan, Yunnan and Xinjiang (positive NRC in total GDP). Regions that experienced
significantly slower growth than the national trend were either the three
metropolitan cities (Beijing, Shanghai and Tianjin), or the backward provinces
in the west (Shanxi, (Guizhou, Tibet, Shaarixi, Gansu, and Qinghai The
central provices and those in the northeast also lagged behind the national
average. Slow growth of the three metropolitan cities were due to the fact
that they were already much more industrialized than any other part of
the country and the fact that their economies were dominated by SOEs and
strict state planning, but poor performance in the western regions was
due to their lack of competitiveness.
It
is easy to note that the growing centres are mostly located in the east,
especially Jiangsu, Zhejiang, FUjian, Shandong, Guangdong, and Hainan.
Positive NRC in Guangxi, Hebei, Henan, Yunnan and Xinjiang implied that
these regions were catching up with the growing frontier. Indeed, as shown
below, Guangxi, Rebei and Xinjiang should be included in the growing centre
model by the end of the data period. The fact that most central regions
had large negative NRCs was disappointing because they were generally expected
to catch up with the growing frontier in terms of growth.
There
are some interesting results at the sectoral level. Although the actual
growth in agriculture was positive for all provinces, in terms of NRC,
all provinces except Saurian had a lower agricultural growth than national
GDR In addition, much of the negative NCRs was explained by the structural
component, implying a clear national shift against agriculture. On the
other extreme, the services sector was the largest gainer in most provinces.
Apart from the three metropolitan cities, Tibet, Shaanxi, Gansu and Qinghai,
all the other provinces had higher growth of the service industries than
that of the national economy. The best performers in services were again
located in the east, including Jiangsu, Zhejiang Fujian. Shandong, Guangdong,
Guangxi and Hainan. In industry, the picture was less clear but the fast
growing provinces were still among the best performers.
The
results in Table 2 make it possible to classify all provinces and cities
into three different development models. The classification
and the basic characteristics of these models are described below.
(1)
The growing centre model. This model included three groups of regions.
The first group covered Jiangsu, ZheJiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong,
Hainan, and Guangxi. All these provinces are located along the eastern
coast with per capita GDPs (except Guangxi) and CDP growth much higher
than national averages. Although Guangxi's per capita CDP was low in the
data period, its growth was one of the highest. The second group included
the three metropolitan cities and Liaoning. They had the highest per capita
CDP and were the most industrialized regional economics. Although their
growth was much below national average, they were still the growing centres
as any growth in these regions would have had a significant impact on the
surrounding areas. The third group consisted of Hebei and Xinjiang. These
two regions had a per capita CDP and growth much higher than the national
average. They were different from those in the first group because of their
inland location and lack of openness in the first stage of economic reforms
in the early 1980s. However, they became two successful examples of the
catching up regions that had developed themselves into a growing centre
(high income and high growth).
(2)
The catching up model. This included most of the central regions (Henan,
Hubei, Hunan, Jiangxi, Shanxi, Anhui, Inner Mongolia), the northeastern
regions (Jilin and Heilongjiang), and some provinces in the west (Sichuan
and Yunnan). Per capita CDP was lower than national average. CDP growth
was high but not necessarily higher than national average. Most provinces
experienced rapid structural changes with fast growth in industry and services
at the expense of agriculture. These provinces comprised over 60 per cent
of the country's population and their performance was a crucial factor
of the overall success of Deng's multi-tier and multi-stage development
strategy.
(3)
The backward model. Guizhou Tibet, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai and Ningxia
belonged to this model. One basic feature was that they were much poorer
than the rest of the country and had much slower growth than the national
trend. These regions constituted a small proportion of the national population
but they were dominated by minority nationalities. They were remote and
mountainous, and hence, had the least prospect of becoming industrialized
and prosperous in the foreseeable fliture. In the data period, they all
had a negative NRC in CDP growth, implying that the gap between these provinces
and the rest of the country was widening, rather than narrowing.
III.C
Changes in employment by province
Structural
changes between three aggregate sectors by province in both actual and
relative terms are presented in Table 3. The NRCs are decomposed into the
structural and residual components according to Equation (3) in the previous
section.
Some
important points of employment changes over the period can be observed.
First, agriculture experienced a relative decline (negative NRC) in most
provinces, except Jilin, Guizhou and Yunnan. Some provinces even had an
absolute decline (negative actual changes). The decline was mainly influenced
by the structural component. This was particularly true in the metropolitan
cities, the southern coastal provinces (e.g., Jiangsu, Zhejiang and Guangdong),
and the provinces with a large share of industry already (e.g., Liaoning).
Second,
the general trend of employment in the industrial sector was a large increase
in the fastgrowing (e.g., Guangdong, Fujian, Guangxi, and Shandong) or
catching-up provinces (e.g., Henan and Anhui), and a slow increase in either
the most industrialised cities and provinces (Tianjin, Shanghai, Beijing
and Liaoning or the most agrarian or backward regions (e.g., Qinghai, Tibet,
Gansu, Guizhou, and Shaanxi). The structural component played a positive
role to the sector's increase in employment in all provinces, but the differential
component played a positive role only in the growing-centre or catching-up
provinces, and a negative role in the rest.
Third,
the increase of employment in services was largely due to the structural
component. The differential component made a positive contribution in some
provinces (e.g., Guangxi, Hunan, 'in).
Guangdong
and a negative contribution in others (e.g., Gansu, Tianjin
Fourth,
the shift of employment from agriculture to 'industries and services largely
reflected the process of industrialisation. The main feature of employment
changes in the metropolitan cities and Liaoning was not expansionary, but
shifting between sectors. Their shares of employment in national total
were declining as a result of low growth high employment growth
occurred due to both structural in employment. For some new developing
provinces, changes and the expansion of their economic scales. It is interesting
to note that there are three different models of employment changes corresponding
to the GDP growth models.
(1)
The glowing centre model which
was characterised by shifting employment from agriculture to industry and
services, whilst overall employment increased rapidly. The causality of
increase was shared by both industry mix and location. In the most industrialized
cities and province (Liaoning), there was a continuing structural shift
out of agriculture towards industry and services although overall employment
growth was low.
(2)
The catching model which
enlarged its employment share 'm industrial sector considerably with a
moderate reduction in agriculture and a proportional growth in services.
However, there were some critical problems faced by those economies that
largely depended on state-owned heavy andmilitary-based
industries. NRC in employment in those provinces performed poorly in all
sectors. There was a serious un? or underemployment problem in the local
economy under economic reforms and rapid structural transformation in an
effort to reform SOEs and break. away from traditional state planning.
(3)
The backward model which
included the backward or the most agrarian provinces where the natural
condition was poor and agriculture played a dominant role. The model was
featured by a continuous Increase in agricultural employment and the lack
of investments in that sector (see below for more detail), an average growth
in industry and a below national average growth in services. Employment
changes (high growth in agriculture and low growth 'm services) were largely
explained by the differential component, or poor competitiveness in the
non-agricultural sectors.
III.D
Changes in investments by province
During
Mao's period, China's development strategy was extremely interior-oriented
(geographically) towards the central and the western regions and military-oriented
(sectorally) towards the so-called ,Third-Front" industries (San Xian
Gong Yue),
industries that were to be hidden 'm the most inland and mountainous areas
for security purposes. As Zhao (1996) points out more than 50 per cent
of national investments went to a few interior provinces, Liaoningg alone
gaining 11.6 per cent of national investments in 1953?62, Sichuan 13.6
per cent in 1966?70. That investments generally received least economic
returns. Since economic reforms from 1978, China has radically changed
the national investment strategy from the interior provinces to the coastal
provinces in the east. A package of economic policies was designed and
implemented on investment, foreign trade, taxation, land -rent, 'm favour
of the SEZs and the open cities along the eastern coast. Since then, investments
were heavily concentrated in a few large and medium size cities and a number
of provinces in southeast China, among which Guangdong (and later on Hainan),
Fujian, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Shanghai, and Shandong were the largest beneficiaries
of Deng's development strategy.
Before
economic reforms, China was dogged by Mao's rigid socialist doctrines which
did not allow any form of ownership but the state's, and by the inefficiency
and lack of competition of SOEs (Yao, 1997b; Liu and Liu 1997; Groves,
et. al., 1994). Deng's economic thought as we have formalized at the beginning
of this paper as a multi-tier and multi-stage development strategy had
two main objectives. First, it was to create a few fast growing centres
that would resemble the NICs in southeast Asia (e.g., South Korea, Malaysia,
Singapore, China's Hong Kong and Taiwan) in order to prove that if other
countries (economies) could make it, so could China mainland itself Second,
it was to create a few capitalist enclaves that did not need to follow
traditional socialist doctrines without direct confrontation with the old
communist guards of Mao's generation. Such fast rig models.
once proved successful, could then be applied to the rest of the country.
Thus, the SEZs and open cities were the cornerstone of the
multi-tier and multi-stage development strategy for industrialization.
They helped break up old traditions and established themselves as the
indusial power houses of the largest developing economy in the world.
Massive
investments into the coastal provinces have greatly improved their economic
position. For instance, from 1985 to 1994, Guangdong jumped from eighth
to fifth place in terms of per capita GDP (only below Beijing, Tianjin,
Shanghai and Liaoning) and from seventh to third in the growth rate rankings
(after Fujian and Hainan;).
Changes
in investments were related not only to national growth and structural
changes, but also to local performance. Table 4 provides the results of
shift-share analysis for all provinces of China. With overall national
investments increased at 134.3 per cent in 1985?94, a significant shift
of investments between sectors took place. Real investments in agriculture
shrank by 45.4 per cent, or 180 below the national average, but rose by
140 per cent in industry and 142.5 in services. Given this national trend,
investment changes by province reveal some clear patterns. In agriculture,
all provinces, except Jilin, Jiangxi, Hainan and Tibet, suffered a real
reduction. By contrast, all provinces (except Qinghai) had a real growth
in both industry and services.
In
relative terms as shown by the values of NRCs, provinces that had higher
than national average growth included Hebei, Jilin, Shanghai, Zhejiang
FuJian, Shandong, Henan, Hubei, Hunan, Guangdong, Guangxi, Hainan and Xinjiang.
Those had lower growth rates were concentrated in the western parts of
the country, especially Shanxi, Guizhou, Tibet, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai
and Ningma. Jiangsu appears to have a low growth rate in Table 4, but if
the investments by the non-state economy were included the growth rate
would be 70 per cent higher than the national average. For other provinces,
including the non-state sectors' investments did not affect the rankings
of provinces because the growth rates of state investments were consistent
with the growth rates of total investments in all the other regions. However,
because total investments by province cannot be broken down by sector,
only the growth rates of state investments are presented.
At
the sectoral level, we can make a few general observations. Firstly, investment
shortage in agriculture spread all over the country, most provinces experienced
an absolute decline. This was closely associated with the structural component
and could be used to explain the instability in agricultural production
over the data period. Although lack of agricultural investments may have
been an inevitable result of long term structural adjustment, an absolute
decline in so many regions may have also reflected the myopic view of local
governments on the importance of agriculture on which more than 60 per
cent of the population depended (Yao, 1996). Secondly, regional variations
of investments in industry and services were mainly related to the differential
components rather than the structural components, implying that the local
factor played a predominant role in attracting investments. The most successful
regions were again concentrated along the eastern coast. The poorest western
regions had the lowest growth rates not only in industry and services but
also in agriculture.
Similar
to GDP and employment growth, the analysis on investments also reveals
three different growth models.
(1)
The glowing centre model which
leant its investment strategy greatly upon industry and services. Consequently,
the local economy attracted large investments, mostly accounted for by
the differential component.
(2)
The catching up model which
also had massive investments in industry and services. In many of those
regions, the growth was much higher than national average. Such regions
included Jilin, Henan, Hubei and Hunan.
(3)
The backward model with
its least competitiveness, had negative NRC of investments in all sectors.
Low investment growth could be explained by the sectoral trend in agriculture,
but for other sectors, it could only be explained by its poor competitiveness
and lack of funds Such regions performed poorly not only in industry and
services but also in agriculture.
IV
Conclusions
This
paper analyses economic growth of the Chinese regions. As there are three
distinct models of economic growth, similar shift-share analyses are conducted
on employment and investments to reveal how closely these important indicators
are related to economic performance.
The
disparity of economic growth between the fast growing centres (e.g., Guangdong)
and the backward provinces (e.g., Gansu) was closely related to different
competitiveness in attracting production factors. It is explained mainly
by local industrial mix in the base year and individual performance during
the data period. Of course some external factors, such as biased government
policies, geographical location and external shocks, also played a role
in the process.
Rapid
economic growth caused significant changes in the national economic structure
which was closely related to structural changes in employment and investments
Structural changes in employment and investments had some important policy
implications. Firstly, the shift of employment and investments from agriculture
to other sectors may be necessary in an industrialisation process and inevitable
as the result of increased agricultural productivity. However, a dramatic
decline of agricultural investments mostly affected the poor in the northwester
parts of the country, including 60 million rural population who lived in
poverty. Thus, if the current trend cannot be changed, it will create more
serious social, economic and even political problems in the future. Lack
of agricultural investments has undermined sustainable development in the
sector which is responsible for feeding the huge and ever increasing population.
Secondly, the relative decline of industry that occurred in both the most
and the least industrialised provinces had different implications: for
the former it meant a forward adjustment towards a more diversified modem
economy with an increasing share of services; for the latter, it meant
a backward adjustment towards a more agriculture-dominated economy. Thirdly,
the relatively high increase in investments with a relatively low increase
in employment in most south-coastal provinces resulted in a much higher
capital-labour ratio than that in the northwester provinces. This will
generate greater inequality in future growth.
By
classifying the provinces into three growth models, it is possible to understand
the complexity and diversity of the Chinese economy in its rapid industrialization
drive. Some high income and the most industrialized regions (e.g., the
three metropolitan cities and Liaoning) suffered from their industrial
mix inherited from the planned system. Although they were considered to
be among the growing centres, their economic growth was much below national
average. This was explained by the relatively high level of industrialization
at the beginning of the data period. The fact that they lacked the dynamism
of the coastal regions suggested that they were struggling to break away
from the former state planning system and to solve the SOE inefficiency
and other related problems. The eastern provinces of Guangdong, Jiangsu,
Zhejiang, Shandong, Hainan, FuJian and Guangxi performed much better than
the rest of the country in every aspect. Hence, they can be regarded as
the growing frontier of China. The successful performance of Hebei and
Xinjiang suggests that it is possible for the inland areas to catch up
with the growing frontier. By contrast, the performance of most catching
up regions and backward provinces was rather disappointing.
Deng's
multi-tier and multi-stage development strategy was to create a few fast
growing centres m a relatively short period of time. It was also hoped
that these growing centres would become the leading regions for the rest
of the country to follow. Successful development in Guangdong and other
fast growing provinces along the eastern coast over the last two decades
suggests that Deng's strategy was a great success in achieving its first
objective. In addition, most parts of China managed to follow Guangdong.
As a result, the whole national economy grew rapidly for a rather long
period of time. The momentum of growth is still high and it is not difficult
to predict that many of the Chinese provinces will be able to achieve a
per capita GDP similar to that of the middle income economies in the next
10 to 20 years.
However,
the negative effects of Deng's development strategy were also clear. There
were more income inequality and political tension between the prosperous
cities and provinces in the east and the poor and backward regions in the
west. The analysis in this paper suggests that the poor regions were unable
to reap the whole benefits of economic reforms. Lack of investments, lack
of skilled labour who may have migrated to the more prosperous regions,
and lack of policy incentives and government support were the major constraints
on economic development. Therefore, the second objective of Deng's strategy,
i.e., for the poor regions to catch up with the rich, remained largely
unrealized in the data period. On the contrary, the ever widening gaps
between the rich and the poor regions were growing and will continue to
grow in the foreseeable future.
References:
Arcelus,
F. J. (1984)'An extension of shift-share analysis', Growth and Change,
15,
3?8,
Armstrong,
H. and Taylor, J. (1993) Regional economics and policy (2nd ed.),
Harvester Wheatheaf, UK.
Berzeg,
K. (1978) 'The empirical content of shift-share analysis', Journal of
Regional Science, 18, 463?469
Casler,
S.D, (1989)'A theoretical context for shift and share analysis', Regional
Studies, 23, 43?48.
Dupn,
E S Jr (1960) 'A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis',
Papers
of the Regional Science Association, 6, 97?112.
Esteban-Marquilas,
J. M. (1972) 'A reinterpretation of shift-share analysis', Regional
and Urban Economics, 2 (3), 246?255.
Fothergill,
S. and Gudgin, G. (1979) 'In defence of shift-share analysis', Regional
and Urban Economics, 12, 249?255.
Griffin,
K. and Zhao, R. (1993) The distribution of income in China, St,
Martin Press (USA).
Groves,
Theodore; Hong, Yongmiao; MeMillan, John; and Naughton, Barry (1994)'Autonomy
and incentives in Chinese state enterprises', Quarterly Journal of Economics,
109,
1:183?209.
Healey,
M. and Clark, D, (1984) 'Industrial decline and government response in
the West Midlands: the case of Coventry' Regional Studies, 18, 303?318.
Hoppes,
R.. B. (1994) 'Rejoinder: industry-level shift-share analysis', Economic
Development Quarterly, 8, 214?217.
Hussain,
A.; Lanjouw, P.; and Stem, N. (1994) 'Income inequalities in China: evidence
from household survey data´, World Development, 22(12), 77?96.
Ishikawa,
Y. (1992) 'The 1970s migration turnaround in Japan revisited: a shift-share
approach',
Paper
in Regional Science: the Journal of RSAI, 71,
2:153?73 3
Knight,
J. and Song, L. (1993) 'The spatial contribution to income inequality in
rural China´, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 103, 122-127.
Kurre,
J.A. and Weler, BR. (1989)
'Forecasting the local economy, using time-series and shift
share
techniques', Environment and Planning A, 21, 753 )?70.
Knudson,
D. and Barff, R. (1991) 'Shift-share analysis as a linear model', Environment
and Planning A, 23,421?43 1.
|